Контрольная работа: Endogenous Cycle Models

Figure 6
- Dynamics of the Kaldor Cycle
The rest of the story then follows in reverse. At E in
Figure 6, we are at a pretty low output level and thus capital decumulates and
so K declines from K2 past K0 and then on towards K1.
In the meantime, our lower two equilibrium begin to move towards each other and
A and B meet and merge at point F at Y1 (equivalent to our old A=B).
Note that the stability arrows in Figure 6 are such that now we must have a
catastrophic jump in output from F to point G (the high equilibrium to which
point C moved to as capital fell from K2 to K1). From G,
the process then begins again as capital rises at high output levels from K1
to K0 and onto K2.
The output cycle that can be traced out from the arrows
drawn in Figure 6 (from slow movement from G to C to D then catastrophic jump
to E then slow movement from E to A to F then catastrophic jump to G, etc) is
Kaldor's trade cycle: output thus fluctuates over time between the boundaries
imposed by the extreme points E (lower bound) and G (upper bound). Notice that
the cycle is completely endogenous: no exogenous shocks, ceilings,
floors, structurally unstable parameter values or ratchets are necessary to
obtain constant cycles. The non-linearity of the curves, which are
economically-justified and not exceptional, is more than sufficient to generate
endogenous cycles.
This version of Kaldor's model is derived a bit more
formally in Varian (1979) using catastrophe theory. However, we can also use
regular non-linear dynamical theory, which makes no assumptions about the
relative speeds of the dynamics, to obtain a cycle from the Kaldor model - and
this is what Chang and Smyth (1971) do. We have already derived the isokine
dY/dt = 0, so to get the full story, we need the dK/dt = 0 isokine. This is
simple. dK/dt = I (Y, K), thus at steady-state, dK/dt = 0 = I (Y, K) so the
isokine has slope:
dK/dY|K = - IY/IK > 0
as IY < 0 and IK > 0. Thus, the
dK/dt = 0 isokine is positive sloped. We have superimposed it on the other
isokine in Figure 7. For the off-isokine dynamics, note that:
d (dK/dt) /dY = IY > 0
so that the directional arrows drawn in for the dK/dt = 0
isokine imply that to the left of it, dK/dt < 0 (capital falls) whereas to
the right, dK/dt > 0 (capital rises). In the figure below, we have
superimposed the isokines for the whole system. As is obvious, the global
equilibrium, where dK/dt = dY/dt = 0, is at K* and Y* (point
E). Now, as we showed earlier, the trace of the system, tr A, is
positive around point E, thus we know that the global equilibrium is locally
unstable - as is shown in Figure 7 by the unstable trajectory that emerges when
we move slightly off the equilibrium point E. .

Fig.7 - Kaldor's
Trade Cycle
However, notice that the system as a whole is "stable":
when we draw a "box" around the diagram by imposing upper boundaries
Km and Ym in Figure 7 and letting the axis act as lower
boundaries, then the directional phase arrows around the boundaries of the box
indicate that we do not get out of the confines of this box - any
trajectory which enters the "box" will not leave it. Indeed, from the
distant boundaries, it almost seems as if we are moving towards the
global equilibrium (K*, Y*). Thus, while the equilibrium (K*, Y*) is locally
unstable, we are still confined within this "box". Note that we are
assuming complex roots to obtain stable and unstable focal dynamics as opposed
to simply monotonic ones.
In fact, these three conditions - complex roots, locally
unstable equilibrium and a "confining box" - are all that is
necessary to fulfill the Poincarй-Bendixson Theorem on the existence of a dynamic
"limit cycle". This limit cycle is shown by the thick black circle in
Figure 7 (not perfectly drawn) orbiting around the equilibrium. Any trajectory
that begins within the circle created by the limit cycle will be
explosive and move out towards the cycle. In contrast, any trajectory
that begins outside the circle will be dampened and move in
towards it. Two such trajectories are shown in Figure 7. Thus, the limit cycle
"attracts" all dynamic trajectories to itself and once a trajectory
confluences with the limit cycle, it proceeds to follow the orbit of the limit
cycle forever (as shown by the directional arrows on the cycle).
In essence, then, all trajectories are "stable", but
we are not speaking of a stable path towards a point (such as an equilibrium) but
rather of a stable path towards another path, i. e. the limit cycle. This is
the limit cycle version of the Kaldor trade cycle. For details on this version
of the Kaldor model and more general non-linear dynamics, particularly on
Poincarй-Bendixson and, more generally, the Hopf-Bifurcation
necessary to yield dynamic limit cycles, consult Chang and Smith (1971),
Gabisch and Lorenz (1987), Lorenz (1989) and Rosser (1991).
Beyond the fact
that these pioneers of non-linear dynamic systems in economics were all Keynesians,
there is a natural fellowship between non-linear dynamics and Keynesian cycle
theory: namely, that non-linear systems, in contrast to linear systems, are far
more capable of yielding regular endogenous macrofluctuations. This implies
that fluctuations are the outcome and indeed an integral part of a working
economy. As this concept was central to Keynes's (1936) static theory, it is no
surprise that Oxbridge researchers insist on endogenous cycles as a way of
extending it into a dynamic context. In contrast, Neoclassical theory seems to
be more apt to consider equilibrium as opposed to fluctuations as the central
feature of a working economy - and thus prefer to conceive of "fluctuations"
as the results of erratic displacements or aberrations from a working economy. The
Neoclassical concept of the economy, thus, is perfectly compatible with linear
systems; the Keynesian concept of endogenous cycles, however, seems to require
non-linear structures.
1.
Dornbusch R. и др. Macroeconomics/ R. Dornbusch, S. Fischer, R. Startz. - 8th ed. - Boston
etc.: Irwin: McGraw-Hill, 2007.
2.
McConnel C. R., Brue S. L. Economics: Principles,
Problems and Policies. - 14 th ed. - Boston etc.: Irwin: McGraw-Hill, 2001.
3.
Speegle R., Giesecke W. Business World: A Collection
of Readings on Contemporary Issues. - Oxford etc.: Oxford Univ. Press, 2003.
4.
Jobs and Economic Development: Strategies and
Practice/Ed.: R. P. Giloth. - Thousand Oaks (Ca) etc.: SAGE, 1998.
5.
Walstad W. B., Bingham R. C. Study Guide to
accompany McConnell and Brue Economics. - 14 th ed. - Boston etc.: McGraw-Hill,
1999.
6.
Макроэкономика: Учеб. для вузов по направлению "Экономика"/ Л.С.
Тарасевич, В.П. Гальперин, П.И. Гребников, А.И. Леусский; Под ред.Л.С. Тарасевича.
- 3-е изд., перераб. - СПб.: Изд-во С. - Петерб. гос. ун-та экономики и
финансов, 2004.
|