Контрольная работа: Endogenous Cycle Models

Fig.3 - Capital
Accumulation and Gravitation of Investment and Savings Curves
So, we can see
the story by visualizing the move from Figure 2 to Figure 3. Starting from our
(old) YC, as I (Y, K) moves down and S (Y, K) moves down, point B
will gradually move from its original position in the middle towards C (i. e. YB
will move right) while point C moves towards B (YC moves left). As
shown in Figure 3, as time progresses, and the investment and savings curves
continue on their migration induced by capital accumulation, and B and C
approximate each other, we will reach a situation where B and C meet at YB
= YB and the S and I curves are tangential to each other. Notice
that at this point in time, C is no longer stable - left and right of point C,
savings exceeds investment, thus output must fall - and indeed will fall
catastrophically from YB = YC to the only stable point in
the system: namely, point A at YA.
At YA,
we are again at a stable, short-run equilibrium. However, as in the earlier
case, the S and I curves are not going to remain unchanged. In fact, they will
move in the opposite direction. As investment is reigned back, there might not
even be enough to cover replacement.
Thus, previous
investment projects which were running on existing capital will disappear with
depreciation. The usefulness (i. e. productivity) of the projects, however,
remains. Thus, the projects reemerge as "new" opportunities. In
simplest terms, with capital decumulation, the return to capital increases and
hence investment becomes more attractive, so that the I curve will shift
upwards (see Figure 4).
Similarly, as
capital is decumulated, consumer industries will disappear, prices rise and
hence real income (purchasing power) per head declines so that, to keep a given
level of real consumption, savings must decline. So, the S curve falls. Ultimately,
as time progresses and the curves keep shifting, as shown in Figure 4, until we
will reach another tangency between S and I analogous to the one before. Here,
points B and A merge at YA = YB and the system becomes
unstable so that the only stable point left is C. Hence, there will be a
catastrophic rise in production from YA to YC.

Fig.4 - Capital
Decumulation and Gravitation
Thus, we can
begin to see some cyclical phenomenon in action. YA and YC
are both short-term equilibrium levels of output. However, neither of them, in
the long-term, is stable. Consequently, as time progresses, we will be
alternating between output levels near the lower end (around YA) and
output levels near the higher end (around YC). Moving from YA
to YC and back to YA and so on is an inexorable
phenomenon. In simplest terms, it is Kaldor's trade cycle.
W. W. Chang and
D. J. Smyth (1971) and Hal Varian (1979) translated Kaldor's trade cycle model
into more rigorous context: the former into a limit cycle and the latter into
catastrophe theory. Output, as we saw via the theory of the multiplier,
responds to the difference between savings and investment. Thus:
dY/dt = a (I - S)
where a is the "speed" by
which output responds to excess investment. If I > S, dY/dt > 0. If I
< S, dY/dt < 0. Now both savings and investment are positive (non-linear)
functions of income and capital, hence I = I (K, Y) and S = S (K, Y) where
dI/dY= IY > 0 and dS/dY = SY > 0 while dI/dK = IK
< 0 and dS/dK = SK > 0, for the reasons explained before. At
any of the three intersection points, YA, YB and YC,
savings are equal to investment (I - S = 0).
We are faced
basically with two differential equations:
dY/dt = a [I (K,Y) - S (K,Y)], dK/dt
= I (K, Y)
To examine the
local dynamics, let us linearize these equations around an equilibrium (Y*, K*)
and restate them in a matrix system:
dY/dt |
= |
a (IY
- SY)
|
a (IK
- SK)
|
|
Y |
dK/dt |
|
IY
|
IK
|
[Y*, K*]
|
K |
the Jacobian matrix of first derivatives evaluated locally
at equilibrium (Y*, K*), call it A, has determinant:
|A| = a (IY -
SY) IK - a (IK - SK) IY, = a (SKIY - IKSY)
where, since IK < 0 and SK, SY,
IY > 0 then |A| > 0, thus we have regular (non-saddlepoint)
dynamics. To examine local stability, the trace is simply:
tr A = a (IY - SY)
+ IK
whose sign, obviously, will depend upon the sign of (IY
- SY). Now, examine the earlier Figures 3 and 4 again. Notice around
the extreme areas, i. e. around YA and YC, the slope of
the savings function is greater than the slope of the investment function, i. e.
dS/dY > dI/dY or, in other words, IY - SY < 0. In
contrast, around the middle areas (around YB) the slope of the
savings function is less than the slope of the investment function, thus IY
- SY > 0. Thus, assuming Ik is sufficiently small, the
trace of the matrix will be positive around the middle area (around YB),
thus equilibrium B is locally unstable, whereas around the extremes (YA
and YC), the trace will be negative, thus equilibrium A and C are
locally stable. This is as we expected from the earlier diagrams.
To obtain the phase diagram in Figure 5, we must obtain the
isoclines dY/dt = 0 and dK/dt = 0 by evaluating each differential equation at
steady state. When dY/dt = 0, note that a [I (Y, K) - S (Y, K)]
= 0, then using the implicit function theorem:
dK/dY|dY/dt = 0 = - (IY - SY) / (IK - SK)
Now, we know from before that Ik < 0 and Sk
> 0, thus the denominator (Ik - Sk) < 0 for certain.
The shape of the isocline for dY/dt = 0, thus, depends upon the value of (Iy
- Sy). As we claimed earlier, for extreme values of Y (around YA
and YC), we had (IY - Sy) < 0, thus dK/dY|Y
< 0, i. e. the isocline is negatively shaped. However, around middle values
of Y (around YB), we had (IY - SY) > 0,
thus dK/dY|Y > 0, i. e. the isocline is positively shaped. This
is shown in Figure 5.

Fig.5
- Isokine for dY/dt = 0
From Figure 5, we see that at low values of Y (below Y1)
and high values of Y (above Y2), the isokine is negatively-sloped - this
corresponds to the areas in our earlier diagrams where the savings function was
steeper than the investment function (e. g. around YA and YC).
However, between Y1 and Y2, the isokine is
positively-sloped - which corresponds to the areas where investment is steeper
than savings (around YB in our earlier diagrams).
The off-isokine dynamics are easy, namely differentiating
the differential equation dY/dt for K:
d (dY/dt) /dK = a [IK -
SK] < 0
as IK < 0 and SK > 0. Thus,
above the isokine, dY/dt < 0, so output falls whereas below the isokine,
dY/dt > 0, so output rises. The directional arrows indicate these tendencies.
We can already get a flavor of Kaldor's trade cycle from Figure 6. Remember
that our earlier Kaldorian diagrams were drawn for a particular level of
capital, K. Thus, as we see in Figure 6, for a given level of K0, we
can find the corresponding equilibria (YA, YB, YC)
at the intersection between the isokine and the level line K0. However,
suppose we start at point C so that K begins to rise: notice that when K0
rises to K2, the points YC and YB begin to
move together and finally "merge" at the critical point D (which
corresponds to our old B=C) at point Y2. The underlying dynamic (represented
by the phase arrows) implies that point D is completely unstable so there will
be a catastrophic jump from D to the lower equilibrium E (which is where A
moved to as K rose from K0 to K2). Notice that during
this catastrophic fall in output is driven solely by the fast multiplier
dynamic - the slower-moving capital dynamic is inoperative as, in moving from D
to E, capital is constant at K2.
Страницы: 1, 2, 3 |